An End to Recessions!
One could argue something like this:
Under current institutional arrangements and policy preferences, the developed countries can have indefinitely long periods of national expansion.The sneaky trick are the three bolded phrases.
- "[C]urrent institutional arrangements and policy preferences": things can change!
- "[C]an" : it;s a probabilistic statement; as long as we aren't foolish enough to stick actual probabilities in there, can't be proven wrong...
- "[National] expansion": puts aside regional and sectoral recessions.
The "can" part of the statement is so-weasel worded that I see no need to pursue it further. But I would underline that if we use some probabilistic phrasing ("the volatility of real GDP growth will be reduced"), things like recessions -- even the Financial Crisis -- could be explained away as a bad die roll. Since most sensible people will stick such qualifiers in their forecasts (the "Great Moderation" proponents did), this is always something to keep in mind.
I will look at the remaining two points.
Current Institutions and Policy Preferences
Since the 1990s, the developed countries followed a similar script for structural changes to the economy (modulo the euro area experiment, which generated corresponding economic outcome outliers in the periphery). The best summary description is "neoliberal reforms," but that term is in the process of losing its meaning in popular discourse. For my purposes here, I have in mind many parallel developments, particular in the Job Market. (In the book Full Employment Abandoned (Amazon affiliate link), Bill Mitchell and Joan Musken point to the "OECD Jobs Study (1994)" as the common thread in developments in the labour market.)
The figure above shows the annual growth rate of real GDP in the United States The vertical red line indicates 1990, which is roughly where we saw the institutional changes happen. Just eyeballing this chart shows that volatility in the growth rate has fallen - particularly if one put's one hand over the data around the 2008-2010 period. Other countries had a similar drop.
Using the terminology favoured by stock-flow consistent modelers, the economy moved to a new steady state around 1990. Economic variables are still changing, but they tend to stick near certain values.
As has been remarked repeatedly, the United States has drifted into a path of lower economic growth since the Financial Crisis. I like to think of this as the "Neoliberal Stasis". This pattern of behaviour is often referred to as a "low pressure economy" by post-Keynesians (as opposed to the "high pressure" economy seen in the early post-war decades).
Analogies to the physical sciences always have to be taken with a grain of salt, but the terms "low pressure economy" and "high pressure economy" are suggestive: physical objects under high pressure tend to blow up, low pressure ones, not so much.
The first volume of my text on recessions could offer a less shaky explanation, but the analogy offers a pretty good intuition.
Thus we can get to the simplified version of the argument: if policymakers keep the economy at a low pressure state, recessions should be unlikely. This sort-of fits the observed data.
The Financial Crisis can be explained away fairly simply. The transition to a low pressure economy involved a steep reduction in interest rates, and this caused a localised boom in housing markets. Regulators dropped the ball on the implications, and the economy "blew up real good."
So long as regulators stay on the ball, total meltdowns like 2008 might be avoided. A Minsky-ite like myself would be skeptical of that, but we will find out. For now, market participants did learn a lesson, and it is unclear how long it will take before the insane risk-seeking behaviour seen before 2007 will show up again.
Localised Recessions
The final qualifier is the use of national recessions. Recessions on a regional or sectoral basis still happen. (For example, the Canadian province of Alberta qualified as having a recession in recent years, if we use a rise in the unemployment rate as a recession definition.)
If you are laid off in a regional or sectoral recession, you are just as laid off as in a national recession. The only difference is that our friendly central planners at the central bank are incapable of doing much to head off such recessions, nor will they accept any blame if they happen. ("It's a healthy rebalancing!")
The business cycle has not been abolished, rather the business cycle is fragmented. We just need to ask what might cause the different business cycles to become correlated again. We might get lucky and manage to avoid such correlation over an extended period.
Concluding Remarks
Dodging national recessions for a long time has been happening in the developed countries since the early 1990s, and it is not shocking to suggest that this might continue.
Publishing Update
If put my manuscript of Recessions: Volume I, aside for a month or so, partly to allow for more feedback. Also, I can more easily spot issues with the text if I have not gone over it recently, as the text is fresh. (If you read a text that you have just written, you tend to read what you meant to write, and not actually the words you put down.)
As for Volume II, I think I will sneak in my "Intermediate MMT Primer" in between. The sequence of articles on MMT I just wrote are effectively one chapter (on price level determination). The next most important chapter will be one on fiscal constraints. Finally, the last planned chapter would be one that offers an overview of the MMT literature -- what to read next? (I am not counting the initial "What is this book?" introductory chapter.)
Once those topics are covered, I am not sure how much needs to be added, I am aiming for this to be a short text that people can read in order to see whether critiques they see in the news make any sense (spoiler: no). I do not care about every single piece of MMT theory, but I just want to cover what the main debates are about, and why most critiques are straw man attacks. The arcane stuff that some people get worked up about (consolidation, the external constraint) are things that only a handful of people care about.
The text will be short, and priced as such. As an ebook, being short is not a problem. However, too short a text makes having a paperback awkward. I might be forced to cheat and change the page size to a smaller one so that the text is not too thin. (I will worry about that when the time comes.)
The key is that I want this MMT primer text done quickly, so that I can go back to Recessions: Volume II. The main research task for me is to get my hands on "canonical" MMT articles to build out my survey chapter, since the financial constraints chapter pretty much writes itself.
Very nice post. I take all your problems, but it seems theoretically possible that we could see an end of recessions, as officially defined, but not of "growth recessions" (to use the Keynesian language of the post-war era). But unlike that period, the trend ("potential") is likely to be much lower to start with, barring major institutional change.
ReplyDeleteBrian,
ReplyDelete"The main research task for me is to get my hands on "canonical" MMT articles..."
In that vein, are you acquainted with "heteconomist"? (Dr. Peter Cooper). Here is a quote from one of my favorite articles of his:
[quote]
Having acknowledged that there are real limits to government deficits (it was never denied), MMT nevertheless makes clear that government deficits are the norm, not the exception. This does not mean that government deficits of any size are okay. They must be consistent with private-sector net-saving intentions. It simply means that ongoing government deficits of some size will be the appropriate policy under normal circumstances. The reason for this is that the non-government sector typically desires to net save. This means, as a matter of accounting, that the government must run deficits.
further down...
Whenever the non-government sector net saves (maintains a surplus), it is spending less of the monetary unit than it earns. The result is unsold output and a signal to firms to cut back production unless the government fills the demand gap through deficit expenditure. By doing so, the government is in a position to ensure all output is sold at current prices and that the non-government sector satisfies its net saving desires. If, instead, the government allows the demand shortfall to persist by not injecting sufficient expenditure of its own, firms will respond by cutting back production. There will be a contraction in output and income, thwarting non-government net saving intentions. If the non-government sector responds by redoubling its efforts to net save, the result is a further shortfall in demand, further contraction of income (as well as tax revenue), more frustration of non-government saving plans, etc. There is no end to the process until either the non-government sector accepts a smaller net-saving position or the government accepts a bigger deficit.
[end quote]
Link to the full article: http://heteconomist.com/krugman-and-galbraith-on-deficits/
You will find a lot of good articles on MMT if you search through his articles.
Hi, I read his stuff, but not as much recently. I tend to follow article recommendations on Twitter, and I don’t see his articles linked there too often.
DeleteJust to clarify - I’m mainly interested in journal articles. Since a lot of the attacks on MMT involve arguing that there is no scholarly literature, so I want to point to those. Everyone is aware that there are lots of articles on the web.
I think this is one of the most significant info for me. And i’m glad reading your article. But want to remark on some general things, The web site style is ideal, the articles is really great : D. Good job, cheers why not look here
ReplyDeleteSo remove the riddle from promoting and become familiar with the demonstrated procedure that is working for thousands.
ReplyDeleteCooperate Identity design