NOTE: This article is an unedited section from my manuscript on recessions. As an immediate disclaimer, this section follows one in which I lay out an explanation of why the yield curve is an effective indicator (which is a re-write of an article published earlier). This section counter-balances the enthusiasm from the previous analysis. This is not a statement of my personal views about the recent curve inversion; I remain agnostic with respect to recession odds. Much of the discussion is generic, and may not be applicable to the current U.S. situation.
Although yield curves (slopes) should be expected to be a useful recession indicator, this will not always be the case. (Once again, I will use “yield curve” as a stand-in for what are more properly termed slopes.) The explanation is that they result from fixed income pricing, and investors trade bonds in order to make money, not provide signals to economic analysts. Anything that puts a wedge between that goal and economic outcomes clouds the signal.
One first obvious point is that bond market pricing could be
completely unhinged with respect to future outcomes. We cannot expect bond
market participants – and by extension, bond market pricing – to be clairvoyants.
We are instead assuming that bond market participants have at least a plausible
chance of making a correct prediction based on available information.
The figure above shows the experience in the United States
If one is charitable towards central bankers, one might expect this to happen relatively often. The central bank senses a softening in the economy, and it snugs the policy rate to counter-act this. Under conventional assumptions about monetary policy, recession should be avoided.
However, the reaction function of modern central bankers is such that this should be somewhat rare. As was laid out in the 2004 “Gradualism” speech by Fed Governor Ben Bernanke,
As a general rule, the Federal Reserve tends to adjust interest rates incrementally, in a series of small or moderate steps in the same direction.He contrasts this with a more direct approach.
An alternative to gradual policy adjustment is what an engineer might call a bang-bang solution , or what I will refer to today as the "cold turkey" approach. Under a cold turkey strategy, at each policy meeting the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) would make its best guess about where it ultimately wants the funds rate to be and would move to that rate in a single step. In the abstract, the cold turkey approach is not without appeal: If you think you know where you want to end up (or are at least are willing to make your best guess), why not just go there directly in one step rather than drawing out the process?The notion of gradualism raises interesting theoretical questions within the context of dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models: the usual formalism to throw out past information, and solve forward based on the current state (as discussed here). Even if forward interest rate rules are smooth, this does not necessarily imply that a model that is re-solved at each time point results in a smooth interest rate path. We will put this curiosity aside, and just look at the immediate implications of this behaviour. Any smoothing behaviour implies a lagged response to new data. (The exception to smooth behaviour is when central bankers panic in response to a financial crisis; creating the downward slash in interest rates that has been associated with recessions.) During an expansion, central banks methodically hike – but the policy rate is slightly lower than it “should be.” (As is expressed more commonly, the central bank is slightly “behind the curve.”) This means that if data are somewhat weaker than expected, the central bank just needs to pause its hiking campaign. Since the interest rate was viewed as slightly stimulative, that should be enough to deal with the “soft patch.”
This tendency is augmented by the desire to avoid changing direction on interest rate movements too often. The convention is that policy reversals are a mistake. This is contrast to the mathematics of fixed income option pricing, which normally assumes that the policy rate follows a random walk (along the path implied by forwards). This is a stylistic convention, and this avoidance could change. However, there appears to be a good reason for this: everyone is well aware that interest rate policy is effected by the entire yield curve. Introducing a great deal of volatility into the path of short rates should raise risk premia (under standard financial theory). Adding unnecessary risk premia into the risk-free curve is normally viewed as a drag on growth. (The author is not convinced by this argument, rather it is my guess as to what the consensus view is.)
We can summarise these behavioural patterns as suggesting that central banks will only start cutting rates when something serious hits the economy. They cannot be too forward-looking either: people generally interpret central bank rate cuts as a signal for recession, and so a downturn in the economy could be self-fulfilling. Therefore, we should not be too surprised that rate cuts tend to happen with a lag after a recession (or financial crisis, as in 1998).
Another behavioural tic is the possibility that the central bank might not cut rates at all when a recession hits. This could be the case for a small “technical recession,” or perhaps the central bank could be staffed by hair shirt economists who refuse to cut rates because oil prices are rising (or similar).
The next fundamental issue that affects the interpretation of the yield curve is the zero lower bound. Since money (e.g., currency in circulation) pays a 0% rate of interest, it was commonly argued that interest rates could not go below 0%. However, we do have experience with bonds trading at negative yields. For simplicity, I will put aside that reality, and first discuss the situation for yields observing a hard bound at 0%.
If all interest rates are bounded below by 0%, and the policy rate is at 0%, it is clear that we cannot observe an inversion of bond yields relative to the overnight rate. Furthermore, holding bonds at low nominal yields is unattractive.
This was famously observed by Keynes in his discussion of the “liquidity trap” in Chapter 15 of the General Theory. (Post-Keynesians typically complain about mainstream economists misusing the term to refer to the policy rate hitting 0%.) However, modern fixed income pricing theory offers an even uglier picture for low-yielding bonds than Keynes suggested.
One of the basic results of option pricing is put-call parity. (I apologise to readers that unfamiliar with option pricing.) An at-the-money put should have the same price as an at-the-money call. This is because we can buy a call and sell a put (at the money) to create a synthetic forward contract. The cost to enter a forward is zero, hence the net price for the option position has to be zero (modulo bid-offer). For fixed income options, the path for at-the-money strikes is equal to the path of forward rates.
There are strong implications for option pricing. If the forward rate is 0.1%, the most an option that pays off on a fall in interest rates (either a receiver swaption, or a call on a bond) has a maximum payout based on a fall of 0.1% relative to the strike. This means that the premium has to be quite small. This means that the option that pays off if interest rates rise is very cheap relative to the potential for the rise in rates. Even if we have strong confidence that the short rate will be stuck at zero for a few years, how confident are we about an interest rate forecast five years from now? (This refers back to Keynes’ notion of fundamental uncertainty.) If that forward rate is near zero, the options market is going to give us nearly free options to hedge that uncertainty. Therefore, so long as you think that the zero bound will hold, you need to be crazy to drive longer-term (e.g., 10-years) too close to zero, as Japanese Government Bond (JGB) investors found out the hard way in 2003 (below).
The Japanese experience with the Zero Interest Rate Policy (ZIRP) conforms to the above description. As seen in the top panel, for most of the 1998-2005 period, the 10-year JGB yield generally stayed between 1-2% (with the previously noted downward excursion in 2003). This kept the 2-/10-year slope positive, and relatively steep when compared to other developed countries at the time. (The relatively high positive slope in the JGB market was the bane of investors who shorted them versus other markets – particularly the Australian market – on the theory that interest rates should converge based on equilibrium considerations.) This is despite the recession that hit in 2001 (based on the declining GDP definition). .) During the period shown, there were no widespread expectations for the possibility of negative interest rates (which arrived later).
Adding in the possibility of negative rates complicates the discussion, but the result is qualitatively similar. The possibility of hoarding currency, or using the contractual right to pay bills early, will limit how far negative interest rates can go. This means that probability distributions are still skewed in a positive direction, and so we should expect the slope to be similarly sticky with a positive bias.
The mechanics of inversion are straightforward. When an issuer defaults, bonds have a recovery rate that is some fixed percentage of the par value. This means that all bonds of the issuer will trade at the same price, which is at a discount to par. In order for a short duration bond to have the same price as a long duration bond, it has to have a much greater rise in yield. Hence, short-dated yields are higher than long-term, and the curve tends to be downward-sloping.
The effects of credit risk may also corrupt some slopes used in analysis. For example, for many countries, it is easier to find short-term rates with a credit component than time histories of treasury bills. This means that economic analysts may take the slope between a risky short-term rate and a risk-free long-term bond.
One may note that the concerns about credit risk are somewhat academic, particularly if we confine ourselves to slopes between central government liabilities. If there is a fiscal crisis, one would not be surprised if fiscal policy tightening led to a recession. However, if one is working with private sector credit curves, it may be that the financial marker disruption is too localised to trigger a recession.
The last area of concern would be technical issues within the bond market affecting pricing relative to the expected path of short-term rates. This could all be lumped under the topic of the term premium. (The term premium is a risk premium that presumably added by fixed income investors to the expected path of short rates to determine the fair value of bond yields.) A later article will discuss the topic of using affine term structure models to adjust slopes to take into account a modelled term premium; the remainder of this section will discuss less systematic analysis.
Rather than discuss a formal notion of a term premium, I will phrase the issue as: can supply and demand affect fixed income pricing so that slopes offer misleading information about the consensus forecasts of bond market participants for the path of short rates? It is clear that this can happen, but it is unclear how significant these effects are.
One initial technical issue is the question of using benchmark bonds. Benchmark bonds can quite often trade at a lower yield than older bonds with similar maturities. This used to be an issue for U.S. Treasury benchmarks, as the bonds could sometimes be financed in the repo market much cheaper than off-the-run Treasurys (“trading special” versus “general collateral rates”), which justifies a premium in pricing. For countries with less liquid bond markets, there can be jumps in yields if the quoted benchmark bond changes. The usual way to deal with these problems is to use a fitted curve. However, this can pose new risks, particularly for maturity points that are near the endpoints of the set of fitted bond maturities.
Another technical issue revolves around banking system rates. There can be high demands for liquidity around year-end (or fiscal year end), and short-term bank rates can spike for tenors that cross the year-end date.
Within the money markets, there is a variety of instruments, each normally trading at relatively small spreads (for example, under 25 basis points) to each other. There can be technical issues that cause wider divergences, and so choosing an inappropriate instrument may give a misleading reading for short-term rates. For example, many entities (trusts and similar) have large cash balances that exceed bank deposit insurance limits, yet they are not allowed to take credit risk. These entities are essentially forced into the Treasury bill market. As a result, a reduction in supply can cause the Treasury bill curve to decouple from other risk-free curves, such as the government bond term repo curve.
The previous factors that affect quoted yields are technical, and could be diagnosed by market practitioners aware of these distortions relatively easily. Moreover, the distortions tend to only amount to 25 basis points or so. The more difficult question is whether supply and demand factors can the bond curve more significantly.
The U.K. gilt curve was the poster child for a distorted curve. The top panel shows the slope between the 20-year and 10-year nominal zero coupon rate (based on data from the Bank of England) for 1990-2004. For normal yield curves, the 10-/20-year slope is normally a small positive amount. As can be seen above, it was negative during the mid-1990s, and then around the year 2000. The deep inversion around 1990 can be related to the efforts to keep sterling in the ERM, which lead to the only U.K. recession during the period shown – using the “2 quarters of declining GDP” definition of recession. (Disclaimer: I need to validate that statement; it aligns with some online sources.)
The distortions in the gilt curve can be traced to the demand for duration created by liability-matching rules for pensions. Pension funds were forced into a tiny market, and prices were bid to stupid levels. This distortion at the long end will then affect slopes such as the 2-/20-year slope (bottom panel).
The question then arises: how widespread are such distortions? My argument is that for most markets, the 10-year maturity (at least) should be relatively free from extreme distortions due to supply and demand mismatches. The private sector has no difficulty in providing a supply of 10-year bonds, and to an extent, duration is fungible. This is not the case for 30-year bonds, as credit analysis on such a horizon is awkward for most businesses. However, if we look at places like Australia (which unusually ran central government fiscal surpluses for an extended period), even the 10-year tenor may have been pushed around by supply/demand mismatches.
That previous argument was qualitative, and probably will not satisfy many readers. A later article will discuss the use of affine term structure models to generate term premia estimates algorithmically – and which raises new issues.
In summary, the bond market is pricing the path of the policy rate. It is possible that rate cuts – signalled by an inversion – may not be a necessary and sufficient condition for a recession. Furthermore, factors in the bond market can lead to a distortion in the yield curve relative to the unbiased forecasts of market participants.
(c) Brian Romanchuk 2019
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Posts are manually moderated, with a varying delay. Some disappear.
The comment section here is largely dead. My Substack or Twitter are better places to have a conversation.
Given that this is largely a backup way to reach me, I am going to reject posts that annoy me. Please post lengthy essays elsewhere.