The conclusions of his article are:
I should add that MMT [Modern Monetary Theory - BR] also does not automatically bias one to thinking that government should be relatively large. Small government advocates would be wise to understand MMT principles given they apply to monetary economies irrespective of the size of government.I think this is the consensus view of the main MMT proponents, as well as myself.
Some MMT proponents that I know support larger public sector provision, while others support a greater role for the private sector. But we all agree on the way that the monetary system operates and the capacities that the currency-issuer holds in that system to further the well-being of the population.
The only qualifier I would add is that the government cannot be too small without there being negative effects on economic stability. My views are based on those of the economist Hyman Minsky. We argued that "big government" stabilised the economy via two channels:
- income-flow effects; and
- balance sheet effects.
Income Effects
Minsky argued that the severity of the Great Depression (and the earlier depressions of the 1800s) was the result of the small size of the U.S. Federal Government. The growth of the modern welfare state has tended to stabilise the economy. In the essay, "Can 'It' Happen Again?" (republished in a book of the same name), Minsky observed the following (on page 12):
In the section "How Big Should Big Government be?" in Chapter 12 of Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, Minsky argued that the (federal) government would need to be about 20% of GDP in order to offset the volatility in private sector.
That said, the mix of government spending matters for counter-stabilisation. For sectors of the economy which are largely immune to the business cycle (at least in the short run), it does not make a great deal of difference whether the firms are run by the government or the private sector. In both cases, employment and investment will be stable, and so it cannot offset volatility in other sectors. As a result, there is little reason to suspect that the changes in the size of government in the post-war era (which largely involved the expansion and decline of government involvement in these sectors) will have a visible effect on economic stability.
Even doing things like having the government run capital-intensive businesses, such as railways, is no panacea. The public sector managers can change investment plans in much the same way as private sector managers. All that may happen is that we replace private sector instability with policy-driven instability.
As a result, what matters most for stabilisation policies is the size of counter-cyclical transfers, such as unemployment insurance, as well as the effect of income and sales taxes.
In "Finance and Profits" (page 57 of Can "It" Happen Again?) Minsky observed:
During good times, the private sector can switch over to more dubious forms of money substitutes to use in liquidity management, as was the case before 2007. However, government money is still the ultimate form of settlement, and the private sector has no choice but to retreat to use government-issued liquid instruments when the solvency of the private financial infrastructure is questioned.
In the pre-2008 system, excess reserves were typically nearly zero. This implied that banks had to replace any reserves lost that day, since the levels of required reserves were fixed during the reserve maintenance period. The fact that reserves were positive was irrelevant, since the deficiency always had to be made up. This required the banks to also use other instruments to bring back those lost reserves.
In the current system, Fed policymakers have stuffed the banking system with excess reserves - at the cost of reducing the float of Treasurys held outside the Federal government. Since Treasury trading (including repos) is a key liquidity management tool for both the bank and non-bank financial sectors, this policy appears to have broken the liquidity management capabilities of the financial system. It remains to be seen how well the system will deal with the inevitable next crisis.
(c) Brian Romanchuk 2015
However, in one respect the economy was really quite different in 1962 than it was in 1929. Federal government purchases of goods and services was 1.2 percent of GDP in 1929 and 11.3 percent of GDP in 1962. This enormous increase in the relative size of the federal government, coupled with the reaction of tax receipts and spending to GDP means that today, much more so than in the 1920s, the federal government tends to stabilize income.The key is that the passive fiscal stabilisers have to be big enough to overcome changes in aggregate demand coming from the private (and external) sector.
In the section "How Big Should Big Government be?" in Chapter 12 of Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, Minsky argued that the (federal) government would need to be about 20% of GDP in order to offset the volatility in private sector.
That said, the mix of government spending matters for counter-stabilisation. For sectors of the economy which are largely immune to the business cycle (at least in the short run), it does not make a great deal of difference whether the firms are run by the government or the private sector. In both cases, employment and investment will be stable, and so it cannot offset volatility in other sectors. As a result, there is little reason to suspect that the changes in the size of government in the post-war era (which largely involved the expansion and decline of government involvement in these sectors) will have a visible effect on economic stability.
Even doing things like having the government run capital-intensive businesses, such as railways, is no panacea. The public sector managers can change investment plans in much the same way as private sector managers. All that may happen is that we replace private sector instability with policy-driven instability.
As a result, what matters most for stabilisation policies is the size of counter-cyclical transfers, such as unemployment insurance, as well as the effect of income and sales taxes.
Portfolio Effects
The other stabilising channel of the central government is via the role of government bonds on private sector balance sheets. Government bonds (where the issuer has a freely-floating currency) act as a stabilising force in investor portfolios, as their price moves are negatively correlated with private sector assets. (In an inflationary period like the 1970s, they all fall in value.) The negative crisis correlation is not the result of luck; it results from the fact that government bonds (and bills) are a critical part of liquidity management in the private sector.In "Finance and Profits" (page 57 of Can "It" Happen Again?) Minsky observed:
There is no way that a financial crisis could develop in an economy in which bank protected assets, mainly U.S. Government debt, were 60 percent of total liabilities.Chapters 3-5 of my new report Understanding Government Finance underline the critical role of government debt in liquidity management within a modern economy with a free-floating currency. Arguably, repurchase agreements ("repos") figure heavily in practice, but a repurchase agreement is just an agreement to buy and sell the underlying security. Government repo trading is just an extension of the cash government bond market; it just sounds exotic because most people are not familiar with it.
During good times, the private sector can switch over to more dubious forms of money substitutes to use in liquidity management, as was the case before 2007. However, government money is still the ultimate form of settlement, and the private sector has no choice but to retreat to use government-issued liquid instruments when the solvency of the private financial infrastructure is questioned.
Reserves Are Not The Answer
The usual assumption is that bank reserves are the liquidity management tool of choice. This in not really the case, at least not from an aggregate point of view.In the pre-2008 system, excess reserves were typically nearly zero. This implied that banks had to replace any reserves lost that day, since the levels of required reserves were fixed during the reserve maintenance period. The fact that reserves were positive was irrelevant, since the deficiency always had to be made up. This required the banks to also use other instruments to bring back those lost reserves.
In the current system, Fed policymakers have stuffed the banking system with excess reserves - at the cost of reducing the float of Treasurys held outside the Federal government. Since Treasury trading (including repos) is a key liquidity management tool for both the bank and non-bank financial sectors, this policy appears to have broken the liquidity management capabilities of the financial system. It remains to be seen how well the system will deal with the inevitable next crisis.
(c) Brian Romanchuk 2015
Regarding the need for Treasuries outside federal government (Fed) this is a Fed paper on the liquidity and federal credit enhancements (read footnotes) of Agency MBS:
ReplyDeletehttp://www.newyorkfed.org/research/epr/2013/1212vick.pdf
Interest on excess reserves (IOER) are effectively better than short term Treasury bills which had lower interest rates post-crisis. So QE provided the aggregate bank with the equivalent of Treasury bills. Treasury provided added assurance of credit enhancements for Agency MBS with properties similar to Treasuries but paying higher interest.
Yes, excess reserves may be more convenient for banks (and interest rate advantages can go either way). But they cannot be used by anyone else. Treasury bills and Treasury repos can be used for liquidity management by everyone (who is big enough to trade repos). The formal banking sector has more position-making instruments than it needs, but this is at the cost of draining the non-banking sector's liquidity. The shadow banking sector is an extension of the formal banking system.
DeleteAnd it is not just the problem of repo liquidity, about which there is a lot of whining. The loss of Treasurys on balance sheets makes investor balance sheets more vulnerable to a crisis. This also effects those investors that do not take part in repo trading, and do not face the same illiquidity risks like banks (e.g., pension funds).
I had some email exchanges on the logic/strategy of QE with W. Mosler. If I understand his main points correctly, in a counter-factual scheme, the consolidated government could insure all bank liabilities and allow unlimited overdrafts at the central bank, it could deficit spend to provide Treasuries, and banks and nonbanks would be able to absorb all of those Treasuries. The central bank would not be forced to do QE.
DeleteIn the circumstances of the bailout (as I would characterize) Treasury had to operate under a debt ceiling, banks were borrowing reserves from Fed in large volume in part because nonbanks were not rolling over repo lending and large (uninsured) time deposits to banks, nonbanks were reluctant to inject new paid-in bank equity, and Fed initially tried to control interest rates by selling Treasuries to offset the increase in reserves due to discount window borrowing by banks. The remedy for Fed running out of Treasuries and controlling interest rates is quantitative easing with nonbanks to add reserves to banks and interest on excess reserves. The solution if Treasury must operate under a debt ceiling or insufficient deficit spending is quantitative easing. I think too many experts don't give the experts at Fed and Treasury due credit for attempting to provide liquidity under factual circumstances. I infer some of the above conditions from levels in the flow of funds.