Pages

Thursday, March 19, 2015

Demographics: The Non-Crisis Of The Dependency Ratio

It is fashionable to wring one’s hands about the impending demographic crisis that is about to hit the developed countries, at least amongst those who want to be seen as serious. There is no doubt that social programmes will need to change over time, but that should not be a shock: one of the definitions of something being dead is that it does not react to changes in its environment. In this article, I look at the demographic situation for the United States, and offer a high level explanation why it is not particularly worrisome. In order to be brief, I am looking only at the capacity to produce real goods and services here, and not the financial measures that are the usual justification for panic.



Yes, The Number Of Old People Is Rising

Chart: Percentage Of U.S. Population 55 Years And Older

The charts above is about the “scariest” one I could come up with for the demographic outlook. It shows the percentage of the population that is 55 years or older. It is rising inexorably, higher, and the usual worry is how can we provide for all of these people?

However, this is just looking at one part of the situation. The flip side of the aging population is that there are people who below the working age.
Chart: Percentage Of Population 25-54 Years Old (U.S.)

The chart above shows the percentage of the population that is in the “prime working age”: 25- to 54-years old.  (The historical data and the census projection do not line up; I assume that this is the result of the exclusion of the institutional population within the BLS data series I used.) Although this percentage will drop going forward, it was actually lower in the mid-1960s. Ultimately, the “dependency ratio” (the ratio of “non-working ages” to “working ages”; shown below) is not hitting some extreme level that will make it impossible to provide for societal needs.
Chart: U.S. Prime Working Age Dependency Ratio


One could argue that children are expected to be provided for by their parents, whereas retirees draw Social Security and pensions. But society also has to pay for education, and many retirees will draw down housing, retirement and pension assets, and those transactions will generate considerable tax revenue for the government.

Coping Mechanisms


There are a number of ways in which society could constructively adapt to an older population. (That does not rule out highly destructive policies, such as we see in Europe. Policymakers there have managed to devastate their economies without requiring help from demographic trends. I leave it to the reader to judge whether the policies elsewhere in the coming decades will be better or worse.)
  • People can work longer than they had planned. Given the widespread failure of market-based retirement provisioning, this is happening already.
  • The economy can return to something closer to full employment, eliminating widespread underemployment. Production does not depend upon how many people are in the 'working age' demographic; it depends upon how many of these people are employed. This alone could compensate for a large proportion of the projected demographic shift.
  • A more sensible attitude could take hold in higher education; students would not spend years in university to end up working in a café. The “requirement” to have a Master’s degree for jobs that were previously filled by undergraduates will disappear. By spending less time in educational institutions, people will end up with longer working lives.
  • Many marginal businesses that can only afford to pay low wages will be culled, redeploying workers to more productive employment. Society could end up with roughly the same "volume" of output, but at the cost of a decrease in the variety of products and services available. (This fits in with a post-Keynesian view that capitalist firms display considerable economies of scale; demand generally constrains output, not declining marginal productivity. These economies of scale do not always exist, such as in resource extraction.)
  • Rich developed countries with ageing populations can trade for goods and services produced by poorer countries with younger populations. (This is already happening, particularly in the United States with its structural trade deficits.)

If the labour market were properly functioning, these adjustments would happen naturally as it tightens due to demographic pressure. That said, there is no sign of this happening yet. Although capitalist economies are meant to be populated with forward-looking firms, in practice, management is myopic and only responds to short-term price signals. (The ongoing overproduction of crude oil by high cost producers at a loss is the latest example of how short-term thinking wins over long-term planning.) Therefore, there is no reason to expect adjustments to occur now in response to pressures that will appear in coming decades. I am not hugely optimistic that any transition will be easy, but reality will eventually force a solution of some sort.

What About Social Security?


I am going to avoid saying anything detailed about Social Security here. The topic has been highly politicised, and a fair amount of nonsense has been thrown around. It is entirely possible that the programme will need to change parameters as time passes, but my first pass analysis seems to indicate that the changes need not be very large.

Much of the analysis of the programme takes place using the fiction that Social Security can be analysed as would a corporate pension plan. We cannot analyse the U.S. Federal Government as if it were a business; we have to analyse government finances by looking at the aggregate behaviour of the economy (I discuss this in the context of government pensions here).

In any event, we cannot transport goods and services through time. Therefore, we cannot do very much in 2015 about shortages of goods and services that may arrive in 2060. (Investing supposedly would help, but there are very few engineering structures that will survive that length of time.)

I expect that I will look at the financial aspects of demographics in later articles. In particular, how will retirement asset holdings interact with government debt ratios? However, the discussion of these financial aspects are secondary to what matters: the provision of real goods and services. And as the dependency ratio projections above show, there is no reason to believe that goods and services will be in short supply based on demographic factors alone [update: typo fixed]. (One may reasonably ask what the sources of energy for transportation will be in 2060, but that has little to do with demographic angst.)

(c) Brian Romanchuk 2015

3 comments:

  1. In a service economy all that will happen is that services will shift towards the elderly and some services that engage people at the moment will cease engaging people and either be replaced with a machine or simply not happen.

    Where market forces don't sort that out (and there's no evidence they will) then government is going to have to start picking winners. Just as they do in a war economy.

    Which means going beyond price as the sole arbiter of value.

    ReplyDelete
  2. Double negative alert (?): "... there is no reason to believe that goods and services will not be in short supply..."

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Thanks, good catch. I must have mangled that sentence during editing.

      Delete

Note: Posts are manually moderated, with a varying delay. Some disappear.

The comment section here is largely dead. My Substack or Twitter are better places to have a conversation.

Given that this is largely a backup way to reach me, I am going to reject posts that annoy me. Please post lengthy essays elsewhere.