Recent Posts

Thursday, April 24, 2014

Did Fed Purchases Reduce 10-Year Yields By 140 Basis Points? Probably Not.

In this article, I look at the paper "Official Demand for U.S. Debt: Implications for U.S. Real Interest Rates" by Iryna Kaminska and Gabriele Zinna (of the IMF, but the paper does not represent the official views of the IMF). Their conclusion was that Fed purchases of Treasurys (Quantitative Easing, or "QE") lowered 10-year real rates by 140 basis points. I explain why I question their methodology.


The paper, like most papers coming out of academia and/or official bodies, is full of a lot of complicated mathematics. Interested readers can look at the full mathematical treatment within the paper. Since I have doubts about their methodology, it is not worthwhile looking at the details of their mathematics.

But to summarise the key takeaways, they look at real rates (specifically TIPS yields) from 2001 to the end of 2011. They fit a no-arbitrage model to the real yield curve using short rates and a demand factor as explanatory variables. They look at foreign official purchases (which was the excuse used by economists why their yield forecasts were too high in the 2000s) and Fed holdings of Treasurys (which is the excuse used by economists why their yield forecasts were too high this decade) as observable variables to fit against the model's demand factor.

They used the stock of debt holdings (as a percentage of outstanding) as well as the average maturity of Fed holdings as measures of the demand pressures. This means that they are using the stock of holdings, and not the flow of holdings as being the operative factor. The implication is that the "demand pressure" is still rising as QE is continuing, even though the flow of purchases is decreasing.

Chart: U.S. 5-year Treasury Yield, Spot And Forward


Side Issue: What is The Time Period We Are Talking About?



Since the data used in the analysis ends in November 2011, I should technically be talking about what was happening then, since that is the point at which their estimate for an effect of 140 basis points was made. And looking at the chart above, yields were particularly low at that point in time. But the problem is that since the Fed has kept purchasing Treasurys, the effect should be even larger in 2014. And I discuss below, that appears implausible.

Problem: Real Rates


The first problem with the paper is that it is specified in terms of real rates. Although real rates are assumed to be important in mainstream economic models, they have no financial significance. There is no fundamental pricing relationship for real rates. Inflation-linked bonds are priced off of two variables:
  1. the nominal interest rate;
  2. expected inflation ("breakeven inflation").  

Nominal interest rates are set in the deepest market on the planet, and those nominal rates are priced off of the expected path of interest rates (and some form of a term premium). Breakeven inflation (at the front of the curve at least), is tied to realised inflation by market participants running breakeven trades against their inflation forecasts. At the long end of the curve, nobody is really in a position to hold trades to maturity, so some rules of thumb have to be used in pricing. Real rates are the spread between these two sets of expectations; they have no independent existence.

The central bank has no choice but to set a nominal interest rate. The fact that we are stuck at the zero bound has an important effect on yield curve behaviour. Since we have only been at the zero bound for a short period, there is no precedent for this effect in the historical data. Thus a technique that ignores the zero bound would not run into this effect until now. The authors are attributing the breakdown in their methodology to Fed purchases, whereas the real culprit is probably the zero bound.

Problem: Maturity Of Supply


The authors looked the maturity of Fed holdings, and they ignore the fact that the Treasury "termed out" their debt over this period. A properly specified model of supply and demand would have to recognise this effect. But this ignored, as they want to attribute the breakdown in their real rate methodology to Fed purchases.

The last time the Fed attempted to influence the economy by changing the maturity structure of their holdings was "Operation Twist" in the 1960s. It did not work then, and the accepted excuse for its failure was that the Treasury did not coordinate with the Fed - it lengthened the maturity of issuance. In other words, exactly what is happening now.

(NOTE TO ACADEMICS: It will soon become clear that QE has failed to accomplish anything. This casts doubt on the loanable funds framework. But you will be able publish articles that take into account Treasury issuance patterns, and use this to "explain" the failure of QE.)

Problem: Real Rate Term Structure Is Unstable


The term structure for the TIPS curve up to the 10-year point is wildly unstable, even if nominal rates are away from zero. This is because the modern U.S. economy only appears to be sensitive to core inflation, not headline. (This may not have been true in the 1970s, as a result of widespread indexation. But that effect has died out before the data set of the paper starts.)

A rise in headline inflation due to higher gasoline prices acts as a tax on the U.S. economy. Economists who predicted rate hikes in 2008 because of the oil price spike were incorrect, which was obvious even in real time. The Fed "looks through" such spikes.

A spike in oil prices could easily raise headline CPI versus core CPI by 1% (100 basis points). This shock will raise a 1-year breakeven inflation rate by 100 basis points, but a 10-year breakeven rate by only 10 basis points (roughly). This means that there will be marked flattening of the TIPS yield curve, which will not follow through to the nominal yield curve.

There are also other technical factors that hit the real yield curve. The crisis in 2008 also blew up index-linked bond curves. Breakeven trades are balance sheet intensive, and many investors were forced out of positions during the deleveraging process. This dislocated the real yield curve.

Problem: There Is A Term Structure For Term Premia


The estimate of 140 basis point premium for a 10-year bond appears implausible. The reason is that there is a term structure to term premia. The front of the curve is more easily traded versus expected short rates, and so term premia there are small. For example, a 2-year bond yield probably only includes a term premium of about 25 basis points.

Note that within this section, I discuss the nominal yield curve, since it is better behaved than the real yield curve.

We can approximate the 10-year yield as:

     10-year yield = ((5-year spot rate) + (5-year rate, 5 years forward))/2.

If  Fed purchases created an 80 basis point premium within for the spot 5-year rate (which is probably way too high an estimate), the premium for the 5-year rate, 5 years forward would have to be 200 basis points in order to generate the 140 basis point premium within the spot 10-year yield. As the chart above shows,  that would imply that the 5-year forward would be at about 6% now in the absence of Fed purchases.

Such an estimate for a fair value for the forward rate seems far too aggressive. Realised term premia have been high over recent decades, but I would argue that this reflects bad yield forecasts by market participants. For example, almost no economists expected short rates would be stuck at 0% for years. The consensus spent a great deal of time trying to explain the "conundrum" of "too low" Treasury yields in the mid-2000s, even though those yield were much higher than the subsequent path of realised short rates.

Since the term premium is unobservable, it will be hard to find consensus on this point. However, an extremely high term premium is hard to reconcile with the depressed levels of other risk premia in other markets, such as credit spreads.

One possible way of defending the paper's results is to argue that Fed Treasury purchases raised inflation expectations while at the same time lowering real rates so that there is was limited net impact on nominal interest rates. This would allow real rates to be depressed, as they argue, while at the same time leaving nominal risk premia at reasonable levels. Such an assertion looks unprovable to me, and I would have to address it in another article given the added complexity of the argument.

Concluding Remarks


Although Fed purchases of Treasurys presumably lowered their yields somewhat, I doubt that the effect is measurable. Yields oscillate wildly in response to expectations shifts, and those expectations cannot be observed directly. Probably the only sensible methodology for investors is to largely ignore term premia, and decide whether rate expectations embedded in bond yields look reasonable relative to their yield forecasts.

See Also:

(c) Brian Romanchuk 2014

No comments:

Post a Comment

Note: Posts are manually moderated, with a varying delay. Some disappear.

The comment section here is largely dead. My Substack or Twitter are better places to have a conversation.

Given that this is largely a backup way to reach me, I am going to reject posts that annoy me. Please post lengthy essays elsewhere.