The chart above shows the long run history of the level of
Canadian CPI; it has a lot of similarities to what happened in the United
States (and similar countries). It is relatively easy to see the change of
regime that started sometime in the 1960’s; the move from a relatively stable price
level to a steady rise.
The chart below shows the latest regime Canada has entered
into since the early 1990’s: a stable rate of inflation around 2% for core
inflation (ex- energy and food prices). This period coincides with the Bank of
Canada (BoC) have an inflation-targeting mandate, with the target at 2%. The
Bank has hit its target throughout the period, for all intents in purposes.
Even if we add in energy and food prices, inflation has been
on target over the cycle: the annualised 5-year inflation rate has only varied
from 1.2%-2.5% for periods ending from 1995-2013.
This has meant that forecasting medium-term inflation has
not been a particularly useful exercise for almost two decades. It was simpler,
and probably more accurate, to take the BoC at its word, and plug in 2% as an
inflation forecast.
From the point of view of a bond investor, it has only been
worthwhile worrying about modeling inflation more accurately if you traded
short-term index-linked debt (under 5 year maturity). But in the case of
Canada, such short-term instruments do not exist. If you are analysing 30-year
Real Return Bonds, you need to forecast breakeven inflation (market expected
inflation) for a long expectation horizon. Those expectations are driven by other forces than what will happen to the components of CPI over the next few months.
Although it is clear that inflation forecasting ended up
being a waste of time for the past two decades, is that true going forward? If you believe that
inflation is essentially 100% under the control of the central bank, you can
worry about a change of objective. If you instead think the BoC was lucky and
hit its target by accident, you could then worry about whatever special factors
held the inflation rate stable could evaporate. And one could easily have made a complacent forecast about inflation in the mid-1960s based on stable realised inflation, with disastrous results.
I do not have a short answer, or even a long answer, to those
questions. My instinct is that the low inflation is a structural phenomenon,
and so it will not easily evaporate even if the BoC misses a few forecasts.
Yes, the BoC inflation target is part of those structural factors, but it is not the only
factor. The similarity of inflation outcomes since 1990 for most developed
countries indicates that there are some other factors in play, aiding monetary policy.
The real risk appears
to be a structural changes to the policy mix: both monetary and fiscal policy.
My reading is that there is no constituency for such a change, at present at
least. All one can hope to do is monitor developments, and see whether the trends
are shifting. And this is not just true for Canada; the same structural inflation
stability is seen in the United States, Australia, and the United
Kingdom (although the U.K. has had perkier inflation). Japan is a
special case of having price level stability.
In Conclusion: medium-term inflation forecasting is not a
modeling exercise; instead it is an exercise of imagining what structural changes will allow inflation to take hold, and monitoring whether those
developments are occurring. To what it extent it matters, I still would keep a medium-term inflation forecast unchanged at 2%.
(c) Brian Romanchuk 2013
This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDelete