Currency volatility is in the air again. This article is a follow up of the article yesterday. In that previous article, I discussed how the developed world was free of domestic financial crises during (most of) the Bretton Woods era. The stability we saw in domestic financial markets during this period was not a feature of foreign exchange markets. Even though capital accounts were tightly controlled within the Bretton Woods system, there were still crises associated with unsustainable rate parities (notably serial devaluations of the British Pound). Forex crises have continued periodically, with the next candidate now moving onto radar screens.
The charts below show the extent of the recent plunge in the
Brazilian real, and the Indian Rupee as important examples of the turmoil in EM
currencies. As a point of explanation: the y-axis shows the amount of the other
currency needed to buy 1 U.S. dollar (USD). Thus, the rapid rise means that it
takes increasing amounts to buy $1, thus a weakening currency.
The currency crises of the Bretton Woods era were of a
slightly different character than recent ones. The earlier crises largely ended
up being political crises (how embarrassing, we have to devalue); the impact on
the domestic economies were fairly limited as international trade and capital
accounts were tightly controlled. More recent currency crises, such as seen in
the Asian Crisis of 1997, have often seen broader impacts. This is as a result
of widespread currency mismatches within the financial and nonfinancial
sectors.
As long as you have fixed exchange rate systems, you will
have currency alignment crises. From a North American perspective, it appears
that European policymakers are irrationally attached to fixed exchange systems
(something in the water?). As a result, European financial history since after
World War I is the study of exchange rate crises; the long-lasting implosion in
the euro area is just the latest episode.
Although I enjoy a good panic as much as the next fixed income
analyst, I am uncertain whether the current emerging market environment will
develop into a full-fledged crisis. These currency moves could just be another
episode of the summer “silly season” in financial markets. With a lot of senior
people away, markets get illiquid and prices can go for extended runs. When
everyone gets back to the desk after Labour Day, it should be clearer whether
these forex moves will lead to further destabilisation. The end result could
just be a relatively benign realignment of currencies (and a few blown out
forex trading books).
And as usual, emerging market policy makers are kvetching about
Federal Reserve policy. James Bullard (head of St. Louis Fed) gave a good
summary of the source of Fed frustration on the weekend:
“They were complaining
about us easing too much,” Bullard said. “Now when we start to talk about taper
they’re complaining about too tight of a policy. They have an independent
monetary policy and they have to use that to manage” their own economies.”
As I noted earlier, Fed policymakers want to exit QE, as
they finally noticed it has done nothing for the real economy. Meanwhile the
policy spawns instability amongst credulous market participants, and it also
creating a political blowback against the Fed, which poses career risk for Fed
employees. Unfortunately, they may yet again be held hostage by self-destructing
momentum investors and badly calibrated emerging market policy settings.
I see no compelling reason yet for Fed officials to follow anything other the U.S. real
economy in the upcoming policy announcement. If the optimistic economic
narrative is upheld by a decent Payrolls number (and/or a continued fall in the
Unemployment Rate), September tapering still seems likely. However, the tapering of the flow could be a tentative $10-15 billion a month, which means there will be a long time to reverse course on
tapering. (Fed officials have argued that increased stock of Treasury holdings is the measure of the size of the stimulus, whereas market participants appear fixated on the flow.
Since QE is broadly ineffective, the stock/flow debate seems rather
pointless.)
If we turn to the larger question of how to avoid future
exchange rate crises, I am not the person to give a solution. However, I am
unconvinced that they can be avoided by new and improved regulation. The
British Treasury was overwhelmed during the Bretton Woods era by industrial
importers and exporters adjusting their accounts receivable and payable (“leads
and lags”). Bankers were conservative members of the establishment, and they
did not have a culture of openly engaging in regulatory arbitrage, as is the
case for the current generation. Without oppressive state intervention
throughout commerce, such as seen in China, there is no way to regulate away
the problems inherent in fixed exchange rate regimes when there is massive
cross-border trade.
Conversely, developing countries with truly floating forex
rates have been currency crisis-free. For example, Canada abandoned its policy
of attempting to “smooth” the Canadian dollar in the early 1990’s once it
became apparent that the policy was just a form of corporate welfare to forex
trading desks. Since then, the Canadian dollar has gyrated wildly versus the
U.S. dollar (Canada’s most important trading partner), and this has not caused
a “crisis” (other than for those on the wrong side of various trades).
I would put down the lack of currency crises in places like
Canada versus emerging markets like Brazil and India as being the result of
balance sheet effects, and not much to do with regulation (there being
effectively none). Canada has relatively deep and integrated capital markets
creating the balance sheet size to absorb flows. Both institutional and retail
investors in Canada have large international exposure in their portfolios
(aided by the fact the Canadian equity index was a real dog in the 1990's). Institutional
investors are very well aware they have CAD-denominated actuarial liabilities
to cover. Taken together, this means there are large natural buyers if the
currency gets “too weak”. Yes, investor herding generates volatility, but that
is actually beneficial from the point of view of financial stability (to paraphrase
Hyman Minsky, instability is stabilizing).
The volatility of the currency prevents foolish activity
like foreign currency mortgages from making inroads. Canadian corporations
often borrow in U.S. dollars, but they typically do so to offset their USD
exposure. Conversely EM policymakers pursue
exchange rate stabilisation policies, and did their best to talk up their
currencies when things were going well. (“The Fed is printing! We need a new
BRIC reserve currency!”) This encouraged borrowing in foreign currency (USD),
and this type of borrowing inevitably blows up.
Unfortunately, I do not see the balance sheet effects seen
in places like Canada appearing any time soon in most emerging markets. As
such, easy solutions to their foreign exchange policy woes seem out of reach.
(c) Brian Romanchuk 2013
This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDelete